Going to another dealer should solve your problem, after that would be small claims but for 1000 its really not worth it.
but if you want to complain, the correct response ( if Suzuki Canada won't do anything ) is to complain to the competition bureau.
VERY VERY SORRY FOR THE LENGTH
http://www.competitionbureau.gc.ca/eic/site/cb-bc.nsf/eng/home
Appendix III: Tying, Bundling, and Bundled Rebates There is a variety of ways in which products can be packaged together by a single firm; these combinations are commonly categorized as tying and bundling. Tying occurs when a firm that produces two or more products requires a buyer to purchase more than one product as a condition of sale; in other words, the firm refuses to sell product A to a buyer unless that buyer also purchases product B from the firm as well (and potentially products C, D, and so on).
[SUP]68[/SUP] Bundling typically refers to situations whereby products are sold together in fixed proportions,
i.e., product A is sold in a package with product B (and potentially products C, D, and so on).
[SUP]69[/SUP]
Tying and bundling are ubiquitous in many, if not most, markets – cars, for example, are usually sold with four tires (a bundle of car and tires) and require service under warranty from the same manufacturer (a tie between product and service). Generally speaking, there are often strong cost efficiencies that motivate tying and bundling; it may be less costly for firms to manufacture and/or package products together, and it may be more convenient for consumers to purchase that package than search for each individual product. This convenience can also serve to increase demand among consumers who prefer to buy the products together. Tying and bundling may help firms achieve economies of scope, which often leads to higher quality products or lower total prices than if each product were forced to be sold separately and may also prompt firms to broaden their product offerings in order to maintain as complete a set of products as that of their competitors. Tying is also often used, like exclusive dealing, as a means of ensuring product quality and service levels, particularly in aftermarkets.
In some cases, demand for a package of products may be sufficient such that that tie or bundle is no longer a combination of individual products, but a product market in itself. The Tribunal recognized in
Tele-Direct that tying (and by extension bundling), in the first instance, involves a determination as to whether there are in fact two separate products, or only one.
[SUP]70[/SUP]
Tying and bundling may also allow firms to engage in various forms of price discrimination. One rationale is metering demand, such as where a firm ties or bundles aftermarket products to the sale of the principal product. For instance, a firm that sells a printer may require that consumers also use that firm’s aftermarket ink cartridges, either through technological restrictions or through exclusive supply arrangements. The net result is that the firm can charge more to high-demand consumers that use the printer more (
i.e., require more ink cartridges). In some cases, the ability to meter can ensure that both low and high-demand consumers are able to purchase the principal product; if the firm can charge only a single price for its product and is unable to meter demand through tying, its profit-maximizing price may exclude low-demand consumers. If it can instead meter demand, it may be able to charge a lower price for the principal product.
[SUP]71[/SUP]
Aftermarket tying that creates exclusivity, such as the examples above of a car requiring service under warranty from the manufacturer and printers requiring ink cartridges from the same firm, is one of the most common forms of tying in consumer markets. As a general principle, aftermarket tying raises competition issues only under limited circumstances. While aftermarket tying may restrict third-party access to service a particular brand, a brand itself will not necessarily constitute a relevant product market if consumers see other brands and products as substitutes, and so the owner of a particular brand will not necessarily hold a dominant position. Where aftermarket tying is common across brands within a particular product market – i.e., most or all of the firms in a market engage in aftermarket tying – the Bureau will examine the extent to which those firms compete for the customer in the first instance. If customers can choose between competing firms when buying the initial product and are widely aware of the subsequent aftermarket tying for that product, the Bureau will consider customers as taking that condition into account when purchasing the initial product, and firms as competing amongst each other across several dimensions of competition, including aftermarkets, when attempting to capture that customer.
[SUP]72[/SUP]
However, there are certain circumstances under which both tying and bundling can be anti-competitive, if they are able to make it more difficult for non-tying/bundling rivals to compete. Theoretically, tying and bundling can be anti-competitive in two ways. First, to the extent that tying and bundling may raise the costs (or reduce the revenues) of non-bundling rivals, it may become more difficult to compete in the market(s) for standalone products, leading to possible exclusion or disciplining of otherwise effective competitors. Second, by discounting a package of products, tying or bundling may constitute predatory conduct. Where that package of products is properly classified as a separate relevant product market (
i.e., the bundle itself is seen as a single product, not a package of separate products), the Bureau will analyze it as predatory conduct to determine whether the bundle, as a single product, is being sold below its total average avoidable cost.
One traditional concern with tying (which can hold for bundling as well) is "monopoly leveraging", where a firm with market power in one market attempts to achieve a similar position in an otherwise competitive second market by engaging in tying between two markets. This will only be considered as potentially anti-competitive if it can deter the entry or expansion of rivals in the second market.
[SUP]73[/SUP] Anti-competitive "monopoly leveraging" is possible only under certain conditions; as noted above, a necessary condition is that it artificially raises rivals’ costs (or reduces rivals’ revenues). For example, if the tie captures enough customers desiring both products to keep rivals from obtaining efficient scale or covering the fixed costs of serving only standalone customers, or if the tie raises rivals’ costs or reduces their revenues by increasing consumer switching costs, for which consumers would have to be compensated, this theory may hold. In industries characterized by important fixed costs of production, this can also occur over time if tying discourages investment in research and development by competitors, or otherwise discourages potential dynamic innovation that would be profitable for competitors only if a larger portion of the market were contestable. Where it appears that a firm with market power is engaging in tying for the purpose of an intended negative effect on a competitor (or competitors) without a valid business justification as discussed above, the Bureau will examine the extent to which this may raise competitors’ costs or reduce their revenues, with the result that competition in a market is substantially lessened or prevented.
Tying and bundling (particularly bundling) can also be viewed as direct price competition. Where it appears a firm is selling a bundle of products primarily as a means of offering discounts to buyers, the Bureau may choose to examine such conduct under a predatory standard, in order to avoid chilling legitimate price competition. In this case, the key issue is whether the appropriate relevant market definition is the entire set of products, or whether component products comprise separate relevant product markets. Where the bundle is determined to be a single product market, the Bureau will assess whether the total bundle, as opposed to individual products within the bundle, is below average avoidable cost. In such a case, the Bureau will then examine whether this will result in a substantial lessening or prevention of competition, namely whether the bundling firm is able to engage in recoupment by raising the price of its bundle once its standalone competitors have been disciplined or eliminated. Where the appropriate market definition is separate products (for example, there are distinct groups of consumers that purchase the bundle and purchase some or all of the products on a standalone basis), it may be more appropriate to assess the extent to which the bundling firm can raise the costs of rivals offering standalone products, as described above.
Bundled Rebates
One specific form of conduct that falls under the category of packaged selling is bundled rebates. A bundled rebate is a practice whereby a firm offers a buyer a discount on a product if that buyer purchases a second product (or more) from the firm as well. For example, a buyer may receive a 15% discount on product A if it purchases product B from the same firm.
[SUP]74[/SUP]
Bundled rebates were considered by the Tribunal in
Canada Pipe. Canada Pipe, which was found to hold a dominant position in markets for cast-iron pipe, couplings, and fittings, offered distributors a stocking distributor program (SDP) that provided a system of rebates based on purchasing all three types of product exclusively from Canada Pipe. The Bureau argued that the SDP acted as a barrier to entry by foreclosing potential entrants and existing competitors from accessing distributors, with the result that competition was lessened substantially in markets for these products. In the Tribunal’s view, however, the switching costs (in the form of foregone rebates) faced by distributors moving their business from Canada Pipe to competitors were not great enough for this barrier to be significant. Ultimately, the Federal Court of Appeal ruled that the Tribunal had made an error in law in applying paragraphs 79(1)(
b) and 79(1)(
c) to the facts of the case, and the matter was eventually settled by a registered consent agreement between the Bureau and Canada Pipe.
Like other types of bundling and tying, bundled rebates may be considered either exclusionary or predatory conduct. For example, bundled rebates to retailers or distributors may have an exclusionary effect on competitors by raising their costs of getting their product or products to end consumers (or reducing their revenues by forcing them to match a discount), just as exclusive contracts would. Just as exclusive contracts render less of a market contestable, bundled rebates can have the same effect if the effect of a distributor or retailer foregoing the discount is sufficient to induce exclusivity or otherwise raise the costs of rivals, or reduce their revenues, to the point where they are less effective competitors.
[SUP]75[/SUP] In all cases, bundled rebates can enhance competitor barriers to entry in any or all of the product markets over which rebates are offered.
At the same time, bundled rebates can be a form of price competition, particularly when they are targeted at final buyers. In this case, bundled rebates may be assessed as predatory conduct, consistent with the Bureau’s approach to predation outlined in these guidelines. Where a bundled rebate comprises a separate relevant product market (
i.e., the bundle is properly considered a single product, rather than a package of standalone products), the Bureau will assess it using a predatory standard. The Bureau recognizes that bundled rebate programs are often complex and may have several different percentage targets depending on each product; it may be appropriate to aggregate these when determining effective product prices for any price-cost analysis.